Why did this year’s Nobel prize-winning economist write about dwarf-tossing and horse meat?

Alex Tabarrok has a good layman’s explanation of the work of Alvin Roth and Lloyd Shapley, this year’s winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics. (Yes, yes, the Sveriges Riksbank etc. etc.) Their work on matching algorithms has been used to more efficiently and satisfactorily match students with schools, new doctors with hospitals, and most ...

By , a former associate editor at Foreign Policy.
CHRISTOPHE SIMON/AFP/Getty Images
CHRISTOPHE SIMON/AFP/Getty Images
CHRISTOPHE SIMON/AFP/Getty Images

Alex Tabarrok has a good layman's explanation of the work of Alvin Roth and Lloyd Shapley, this year's winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics. (Yes, yes, the Sveriges Riksbank etc. etc.) Their work on matching algorithms has been used to more efficiently and satisfactorily match students with schools, new doctors with hospitals, and most famously, patients with donor organs.

Alex Tabarrok has a good layman’s explanation of the work of Alvin Roth and Lloyd Shapley, this year’s winners of the Nobel Prize in Economics. (Yes, yes, the Sveriges Riksbank etc. etc.) Their work on matching algorithms has been used to more efficiently and satisfactorily match students with schools, new doctors with hospitals, and most famously, patients with donor organs.

One of Roth’s more interesting notions, and one that may be of particular interest to FP readers, is his work on repugnance as a constraint on markets — the costs imposed by the fact that certain cultures find the buying and selling of certain goods and services to be too icky.

Roth was particularly interested in cultural taboos against the buying and selling of organs. We may find the idea of a teenager selling his kidney for an iPad 2 to be beyond acceptable market behavior, but many economists argue that this squeamishness should not stand in the way of either a destitute person willing to sell a kidney for money, or an ill person willing to pay to stay alive. 

In his 2007 paper, Repugnance as a Constraint on Markets, Roth considers several examples of repugnancy costs.  For instance, it is illegal to eat horse meat in California. But it is not illegal to kill horses — just not for the purpose of eating them — and many people in the state come from societies where eating horse is socially acceptable.  

He also discusses dwarf-tossing, an activity banned in many places and widely viewed as morally repugnant, though the physically similar sport of "wife-carrying," is widely accepted. Roth notes that a dwarf-tossing ban in France was overturned after one dwarf sued on the grounds that it violated his right to employment. 

In less wacky sections, Roth discusses why carbon trading schemes are now considered acceptable, but it is considered unethical to pay developing countries to take in waste from the rich world, any why paying mercenaries is considered less ethical than expecting young citizens to die for their country.There’s also the charging of interest, a practice that only being acceptable in Europe around the 14th and 15th century and is still considered unethical in Islamic societies today, resulting in a cottage industry of sharia-compliant financial services.

Roth concludes by arguing that "the real repugnance that some people feel toward some transactions means that economists interested in proposing and designing markets must take this repugnance into account."

If one hopes to design more efficent and ethical systems of exchange, cultural notions of repugnance can’t simply be dismissed as irrational. This would seem to be an argument with implications beyond economics. 

Joshua Keating was an associate editor at Foreign Policy. Twitter: @joshuakeating

Tag: War

More from Foreign Policy

An illustration shows the Statue of Liberty holding a torch with other hands alongside hers as she lifts the flame, also resembling laurel, into place on the edge of the United Nations laurel logo.
An illustration shows the Statue of Liberty holding a torch with other hands alongside hers as she lifts the flame, also resembling laurel, into place on the edge of the United Nations laurel logo.

A New Multilateralism

How the United States can rejuvenate the global institutions it created.

A view from the cockpit shows backlit control panels and two pilots inside a KC-130J aerial refueler en route from Williamtown to Darwin as the sun sets on the horizon.
A view from the cockpit shows backlit control panels and two pilots inside a KC-130J aerial refueler en route from Williamtown to Darwin as the sun sets on the horizon.

America Prepares for a Pacific War With China It Doesn’t Want

Embedded with U.S. forces in the Pacific, I saw the dilemmas of deterrence firsthand.

Chinese Foreign Minister Wang Yi, seen in a suit and tie and in profile, walks outside the venue at the Belt and Road Forum for International Cooperation. Behind him is a sculptural tree in a larger planter that appears to be leaning away from him.
Chinese Foreign Minister Wang Yi, seen in a suit and tie and in profile, walks outside the venue at the Belt and Road Forum for International Cooperation. Behind him is a sculptural tree in a larger planter that appears to be leaning away from him.

The Endless Frustration of Chinese Diplomacy

Beijing’s representatives are always scared they could be the next to vanish.

Turkey's President Recep Tayyip Erdogan welcomes Crown Prince of Saudi Arabia Mohammed bin Salman during an official ceremony at the Presidential Complex in Ankara, on June 22, 2022.
Turkey's President Recep Tayyip Erdogan welcomes Crown Prince of Saudi Arabia Mohammed bin Salman during an official ceremony at the Presidential Complex in Ankara, on June 22, 2022.

The End of America’s Middle East

The region’s four major countries have all forfeited Washington’s trust.