Fragile Europe, Exposed and Unmoored
The fig leaf that was covering up the flaws in the single currency system has finally fallen off. Where do we go from here?
Greece’s July 5 referendum has made clear what Alexis Tsipras and his government had been saying for months: The terms of the international bailout that the so-called troika -- the European Commission, the European Central Bank, and the International Monetary Fund -- offered to Greece (and had partially withdrawn) are unacceptable. With 87 percent of the votes counted by Sunday afternoon, more than 60 percent of voters have rejected the bailout.
Greece’s July 5 referendum has made clear what Alexis Tsipras and his government had been saying for months: The terms of the international bailout that the so-called troika — the European Commission, the European Central Bank, and the International Monetary Fund — offered to Greece (and had partially withdrawn) are unacceptable. With 87 percent of the votes counted by Sunday afternoon, more than 60 percent of voters have rejected the bailout.
Having gone through a rather inflexible set of measures to substantially reduce the budget deficit within a relatively short time span, in 2014 Greece expended a great deal of effort to achieve a primary surplus of 1.9 billion euros, but still fell short of the 4.9 billion euro target. When asked whether they wanted to stick with more or less the same austerity policies, the Greeks rationally said “no.” With the country’s unemployment rate currently at 25 percent, the size of the economy is 25 percent smaller than it was in pre-crisis years. On top of which, Greece’s public debt stands at approximately 177 percent of GDP; it was 157 percent in 2012. Why should the Greek people have voted “yes” in the referendum? To continue with the same painful and inconclusive measures?
But Sunday’s referendum has been more than just a mechanism for voters to express their preferences and change the course of policy. It has also challenged the framing of Greece’s predicament.
The country’s creditors had implicitly bundled together Greek voters’ acceptance of the bailout terms and their willingness to live within the “rules” of Europe’s monetary union. As a result, the referendum was treated unnecessarily — and dangerously — as a binary choice: Either keep austerity and accept the euro, or reject it and leave. As Jean-Claude Juncker, the president of the European Commission made clear a few days before the referendum, “’no’ would mean that Greece is saying no to Europe.”
But for Greeks, it was never so clear cut. And now, what some have called “deliberate ambiguity” on the part of Tsipras and his government could pay off. Hopefully — and this would be the best scenario — the Greeks have not said “no” to Europe, and so Europe should not say “no” to Greece. Thus, negotiations should resume between Greece and its creditors to find a compromise and agree on a mutually acceptable solution to the sovereign debt crisis. But short of a substantial debt restructuring that gives Greece the necessary fiscal space to rekindle economic growth and the supply-side reforms — such as, for example, the liberalization of professional services — that are needed to make the economy more efficient, it is difficult to see any substantial improvement on the current deadlock, with Greece keeping the euro while mired in constant negotiations over its debts and economic policies as successive payments come due.
This gloomy scenario implies protracted political uncertainty, market instability, and an unhappy future, in which the level of animosity perilously increases in Greece and elsewhere in Europe as support for the union’s single currency dwindles everywhere — especially in the euro periphery — and euro skepticism continues to rise. (Already, for instance, just some 56 percent of Italians back the euro.) And so the game of who should be blamed for the Greek crisis — the current government, previous governments, the troika, the Germans, and so on — continues, with the additional risk of fomenting divisions, nationalism, and even racism; all sentiments that the European project was intended to contain and offset.
The unfolding of the Greek crisis has exposed the fundamental fragility of the European construction. Europe was built on the idea that supporting a common currency and common economic interests would always prevail in domestic politics and voters’ preferences. This might be true when good economic conditions translate into growth and job creation across the board, and indeed the initial years of Europe’s monetary union were a resounding success. But is it plausible to expect countries to stick to their commitments when the going gets tough?
Almost two decades after its creation, it is screamingly obvious that Europe’s monetary union is neither an optimal currency area nor a strong political project; for years, politics has provided the fig leaf to cover the single currency’s economic flaws. At best, the monetary union is a half-baked experiment with huge shortfalls in its institutional design. At worst, it is an unsustainable mess where voters’ preferences in one country (for instance, support for more accommodating fiscal policies) sometime conflict with the preferences of voters in another country (for instance, support for more fiscal “probity”). This is what is happening in Europe, and it is too simplistic to push the blame on the Germans or on Greece — or even on the troika.
Where do we go from here? It is critical to reflect on whether there is room to turn Europe’s monetary union into a fiscal union and eventually into a political union. This would mean not only embracing the harmonization of standards and regulations that would underpin the single market and the single currency, but also sharing the burden of adjustment and accepting, for example, fiscal transfers from a “euro” budget to countries that experience financial hardship. Of course, a eurozone-wide political framework implies that member states would need to surrender a good deal of sovereignty and create “euro” institutions that are accountable to and representative of all euro citizens. But if this option goes against the preferences of the eurozone member states and their citizens, then the monetary union needs to be transformed into a mechanism for sharing a common currency that members can leave when they cannot adjust.
Neither of the two options are easy to implement and would require significant institutional transformation. But doing and redoing the same thing in order to keep together conflicting goals and preserving the status quo is no longer tenable. It is, perhaps, too early to say if the Greek referendum has patched up the crisis or has made things worse. However, unless some fundamental change is soon made to the monetary union’s institutional design, it is a just a matter of time before the next crisis turns fatal.
Photo credit: Sean Gallup/Getty Images
More from Foreign Policy

A New Multilateralism
How the United States can rejuvenate the global institutions it created.

America Prepares for a Pacific War With China It Doesn’t Want
Embedded with U.S. forces in the Pacific, I saw the dilemmas of deterrence firsthand.

The Endless Frustration of Chinese Diplomacy
Beijing’s representatives are always scared they could be the next to vanish.

The End of America’s Middle East
The region’s four major countries have all forfeited Washington’s trust.